Trade, Labor Standards and Global Governance: A Developing Country’s Perspective
José Manuel Salazar-Xirinachs *
December 10, 2001
Lecture in the Conference “International
Economic Governance and Non-Economic
Concerns: Transparency, Legitimacy
and International Economic Law”
Research Institute for European
Affairs
Vienna University of Economics
and Business Administration
December 10-11, 2001
Introduction
I would like to start by expressing my appreciation to
the Research Institute for European Affairs, Vienna
University of Economics and Business Administration and
the Federal Economic Chamber of Austria for
their invitation to contribute a paper and to participate
in this Conference. For me it is a privilege to
participate in this meeting and I look forward to our
discussions.
I think the idea that the regulatory framework of globalization
should have a set of universally agreed human
rights regarding working conditions or labor standards
is by now widely shared, and this is, in itself, a
remarkable feature of the new realities in the global
economy. However, the question of whether, and if so,
how to link labor provisions with trade agreements has
been and remains one of the most controversial.
The paper I prepared for this Conference has five main
parts, and I would also like to follow this structure
and divide my intervention today in five parts:
1) First, as background I would like to comment on some
fundamental issues about the relationship between
global governance and development.
2) Second, some comments on the evolution of international regulation of labor issues
3) Third, I am going to enumerate and briefly assess the
main arguments in favor of including labor
provisions in trade agreements.
4) Fourth, I would like to review the main reasons why
most developing countries are opposed to link trade
agreements with labor standards, particularly if it involves
restrictions to market access
5) And finally, I am going to look into three recent models
of labor cooperation agreements negotiated on
the side of trade agreements in the Americas. There are
some lessons to be learned from them.
I. Global Governance and Development
So let me start by reminding you of some of the fundamental
questions that are being posed about
globalization, and which are relevant to the trade-labor
interface, indeed that provide the background for the
central concerns of this conference:
• First, is it correct that global trade and market governance
have developed more quickly than global social
governance? Is there an imbalance between the economic
and social pillars of the global governance
system?
• Second, if globalization is a strongly technology-driven
process, and we are going to have more
globalization whether we like it or not, then what are
the appropriate rules and institutions for international
governance? And who defines these rules? And how participatory
is the process, both in terms of nation
states and in terms of sectors or NGOs within nations?
• Third, what should be the role of the WTO in international
governance vis-à-vis other international
institutions? Specifically, should the WTO agenda be expanded
to include new areas of international and
domestic regulation such as labor and the environment?
Is this expansion of the agenda in the WTO and
centralization of the power to make and enforce rules
desirable? Or is decentralization and specialization in
the allocation of power for rule making in functional
areas better as a global architecture? As I will explain in
a few minutes, in Doha, some of these questions received
a very specific answer that should settle some of
these issues in the next few years.
For the moment let me just say that these are all legitimate
and important questions. However, if the
objective is to promote development and design development-friendly
international policies, institutions and
rules then there is some risk in taking these questions
as your starting point. The risk is associated with the
fact that there is a certain bias in these questions towards
reasoning from the perspective of an industrial
country consensus about the modern market economy and
its institutions. I think a special effort must be
made to have as a starting point a development perspective.
This is important because where you stand in
terms of the trade-labor nexus depends to an important
degree on your views about development and its
fundamental determinants.
From a development perspective there are two debates that are particularly relevant.
• One is the issue of the nature of the linkages between
increased trade and market access, growth and
poverty. Research shows clearly that growth matters for
poverty reduction, and that trade matters for
growth. Faster growth is associated with faster poverty
reduction, and economic contraction is associated
with increased poverty. For poverty to increase with economic
growth, there would have to be a drastic
worsening of income distribution, and this is not generally
the case in most countries. But it is also equally
clear that growth by itself does not necessarily improve
income distribution, and that this requires a complex
array of accompanying social policies.1 The point
that stands out clearly is that development requires
growth and that increased market access and expanded trade
is one of the major contributions that the
world trading system can make to growth and poverty reduction.
• The second debate is about the role of rules and institutions
in development. The international community
has re-discovered that institutions matter for development,
but what kind of institutions? I think institutionalist
economists are right in arguing that the state and the
market can be combined in many different ways, that
there are many different models of the mixed economy that
can promote growth. As Dani Rodrik has noted
in a recent paper on Development Strategies for the Next
Century: “There is no single mapping between a
well-functioning market and the form of non-market institutions
required to sustain it. This finds reflection in
the wide variety of regulatory, stabilizing and legitimizing
institutions that we observe in today’s advanced
industrial societies… We need to maintain a healthy skepticism
towards the idea that a specific type of
institution – a particular form of corporate governance,
social security system, or labor market legislation, for
example- is the only type that is compatible with a well
functioning market.” (Rodrik, 2001, p11) This point
about institutional diversity is a healthy warning against
a simplistic importation of international rules and
standards that might not fit the specificities of developing
countries.
Let me now turn comment for a couple of minutes on the
evolution of international and regional regulation of
labor issues.
II. International and Regional Regulation of Labor Issues
As you know, there is a long tradition of international
coordination of labor law around the ILO. The 1990s
saw a growing international consensus on a number of core
labor rights that led to the 1998 ILO Declaration
on Fundamental Principles and Rights at Work that binds
the 175 ILO members. The core labor rights are:
1. freedom of association and the effective recognition
of the right to collective bargaining,
2. the elimination of all forms of forced or compulsory
labor,
3. the effective abolition of child labor, and
4. the elimination of discrimination in respect of employment
and occupation.”
However, one thing is reaching a consensus based on general
rights or values, and quite another to translate
core labor rights into operationally uniform and enforceable
labor standards.
In a recent paper Drusilla Brown (2001) analyzes some of
the difficulties of defining common labor
standards as well as the complex relationships between
labor standards and economic efficiency. The author
concludes that “Taking steps to reduce forced labor, child
labor, and discriminatory behavior, or to support
free association and collective bargaining will often
have a mixture of effects… We cannot make a general
statement that universal labor standards derived from
commonly held moral values will always produce
positive economic outcomes. The effect on economic performance
and the lives of workers and their
families of legally imposed labor market constraints of
the sort contemplated by labor rights activists cannot
be presumed to be positive, but instead must be empirically
investigated on a country-by-country basis.” (p
97). The point here is that although from a rights perspective
there is nearly universal consensus on core
labor rights, adopting uniform labor standards in operative
terms is controversial.
As regards labor cooperation programs in the Americas,
the thirty-four countries in the Western Hemisphere
have a fairly good record of ratifying ILO conventions
(Table 2). The countries also have a tradition of
cooperation on labor issues, which has been strengthened
by the Summit of the Americas process.
Ministers of Labor of the hemisphere meet every two years.
At their meeting in Viña del Mar, Chile, in 1998
the Ministers of Labor agreed on a Plan of Action, and
established two working groups: one on
Globalization of the Economy and its Social and Labor
Dimensions; and another on Modernization of the
State and Labor Administration.
Ministers identified priority areas and have a number of
initiatives to make progress in each area, including:
the role of the Ministries of Labor, employment and the
labor market, vocational training, labor relations and
basic workers’ rights, social security, health and safety,
enforcement of national labor laws and
administration of justice in the labor area, and social
dialogue.?
The Inter-American Conference of Ministers of Labor met
again in Washington DC in February 2000 and
the last meeting took place last October 17-19 in Ottawa,
Canada. In this last meeting Labor Ministers
established two working groups: one to examine the labor
dimensions of the Summit Process and improve
hemispheric cooperation on labor issues. The other group
has the objective of strengthening the capacity of
labor ministries to enforce labor legislation.
III. Assessment of the Case for Inclusion of
Labor Provisions in Trade
Agreements
So with these comments and information as a background,
let me turn to the question of what are the
arguments that have been put forward to justify the inclusion
of labor provisions in trade agreements? These
arguments can be grouped in four categories: common sense
arguments; moral arguments; economic; and
institutional arguments.
Common Sense and Trade-Relatedness
The basic common sense argument for linkage says that since
trade and labor issues are intimately related,
there should be no reason to oppose linkage. Although
widely used in political discourse, particularly by
trade union leaders, and perhaps appealing to the intuition,
this is not a good enough basis to make decisions
in this area. For instance, trade and income distribution
issues are also related. Should there be an income
distribution clause in trade agreements? I think a common
sense approach does not take us very far. Now,
departure from common sense can take two directions. One
is a pragmatic view: trade-related is anything
governments decide to define as trade-related. This realpolitik
view has some merit, and according to many
it was precisely this that led to the inclusion of IPRs
in the Uruguay Round. The other direction is analytical
and Keith Maskus (2000), for instance, has developed an
interesting framework to analyze
trade-relatedness.
Moral Arguments
The second category of arguments is moral. The typical
moral concern says that: “We should not do
business with countries that violate labor or human rights”.
This idea poses a complex set of issues. First, I
think a distinction should be made between the rationale
for sanctions against regimes that systematically
violate labor and human rights as a matter of policy,
and the rationale for using market access restrictions as
a lever or stick to deal with labor standards in the context
of economic integration among countries with
shared economic and political values but in different
stages of development. These are two completely
different realities and the corresponding policies should
also be different.
Second, if it is accepted that trade is good for growth
and living standards, and if the moral concern is about
the well being of the majority of the poor in developing
countries, then one must conclude that limiting trade
does not help people in developing countries, it actually
punishes them. This is not an argument against
including trade provisions in trade agreements per se,
but one against using a trade sanctions approach.
A related consideration is that, in the case of child labor,
for example, less than 5% of child laborers in
developing countries are employed in export industries,
95% of the problem lies in the non-tradable sectors.
Therefore, even if morally well intended, a sanctions
approach to compliance with labor standards fails to
have any effect on the non-tradable sectors and the general
conditions of underdevelopment that are actually
at the root of the child labor problem.
Economic Arguments.
The third category of concerns behind the pressures to
include labor provisions in trade agreements is
economic. There are four basic sets of economic issues:
1. The race to the bottom argument,
2. The idea that to compete with countries where low-wages
prevail is unfair competition
3. The notion that trade liberalization without harmonization
of labor standards is bad for wage dispersion
and income distribution in the north, and
4. The concern about job dislocation and displacement
produced by competing imports.
Let me briefly comment on each one of these issues.
Race to the bottom
The race to the bottom refers to the fear that in the absence
of international coordination, countries will have
an incentive to lower their own standards to be more attractive
to foreign investment or to gain a competitive
advantage. Notwithstanding how appealing this argument
may look intuitively, there is simply no evidence to
support it. A review of the relevant literature suggest
the following:
• As regards export performance one of the principal findings
of the well-known OECD 1996 study was
that there is no evidence that countries with low core
labor standards enjoy a better global
export-performance than high-standards countries. And
the 2000 update of this study states that this finding
has not been challenged by new evidence. A study by Aggarwal
(1995) concludes that comparisons across
more export-oriented and less export-oriented sectors
indicate that core labor standards are often lower in
less export-oriented or non-trade sectors.
• As regards investment, studies of investment location
decisions of multinational companies show that these
decisions are influenced by many factors of which critical
ones are political and macroeconomic stability,
quality of infrastructure, logistics and of labor skills,
rather than low quality of labor standards.
• In addition, the 2000 OECD study concludes that: “With
the notable exception of China, countries where
core labor standards are not respected continue to receive
a very small share of global investment flows.
There is no evidence that low-standards countries provide
a haven for foreign firms.” (OECD, 2000, 13).
• As regards wage levels, the evidence is clear that wages
in Export Processing Zones tend to be higher than
average wages in the rest of the economy.
Thus, there is no conclusive evidence that export performance
or FDI flows are correlated with low labor
standards of low wages. In fact, labor standards and wages
are higher in export sectors than in non-traded
sectors. Even in cases where there might be an incentive
to lower standards, democracy, accountability,
strong local institutions and international cooperation
are probably the best deterrent for any country to
engage in such race.
Low wage competition is unfair competition
Let me now turn to the idea that to compete based on low-wages
is unfair competition. This argument rests
on two implicit assumptions: (a) that low-income countries
have discretion to define the level of wages, and
(b) that a competitive advantage based on low wages is
illegitimate and consequently unfair. Neither of these
propositions is good economics or is supported by solid
evidence.
The level of wages in an economy is determined by the relative
factor endowments, the skill profile of the
labor force, the general standard of living, technological
conditions and the growth of productivity over time.
In other words, it is closely linked to the stage of development
of a country. So except on the margin, it is
not a variable that the government can establish by decree
to gain a comparative advantage. Differences in
factor endowments and their relative prices have always
been part of legitimate advantages in trade. The
2001 Communication from the European Commission on Promoting
Core Labor Standards recognizes this
by adopting the position that the comparative advantage
of countries, particularly low-wage developing
countries, must in no way be put into question. (European
Commission, 2001).
Impact of trade with low-wage economies on industrial economies
The third set of economic concerns is linked to the perception
that increased trade with low-wage
economies, has contributed to wage dispersion and income
inequality in the North, particularly by hurting
employment and income of unskilled workers. It is a fact
that since the early 1980s the United States has
experienced a fall in real wages of the lowest skilled
workers, measured either in real terms or relative to
wages of high-skilled workers; a fall in the relative
employment of less-skilled workers; and, as a result, an
increase in the share of total labor income going to high-skilled
workers.
Many volumes and papers have been written on these issues.
Two main factors are widely cited as possible
explanations of these changes: international competition
from low-wage countries and skill-biased
technological change that has increased the demand for
skilled workers. As a recent volume and survey of
this literature by the National Bureau of Economic Research
concludes: “A large amount of research during
the past two decades has sought to evaluate both explanations,
with the result that … skill-biased
technological change is often thought to be more important”.
(Feenstra, 2000, p 3).
A variation of this literature analyses not just the differences
in the level of wages but the associated question
of whether wages are related to labor standards. No robust
relationship is found between labor standards
and the level of wages. A recent survey concludes that
in general, the link from low labor standards in
low-income countries to the wage of unskilled workers
in industrialized countries is not strong. (Drusilla
Brown, 2001, p 99).
In conclusion, the notion that trade liberalization without
harmonization of labor standards is bad for wage
dispersion and income distribution in the North, is not
well supported by the available evidence.
Job dislocation and displacement
Finally, as regards the job dislocation effect, it is clear
that trade and the shifting pattern of comparative
advantage can indeed produce job displacement and dislocation.
In fact, from a Schumpeterian perspective
this is essential for the process of “creative destruction”
that drives a healthy process of economic
transformation and provides vitality to capitalist economies.
The right response to this effect is not to resist
these changes with protectionist responses but rather
to facilitate adjustment via trade adjustment assistance
policies, including income support, retraining programs,
workers relocation and other safety nets
mechanisms. Of course, there is a complex political economy
dynamics behind any such process and
countries must be able to afford these programs. In addition,
it must be recognized that the WTO and trade
agreements have mechanisms such as transition periods,
safeguards against import surges, anti-dumping, and
others that can be used to help workers and industries
to adapt to the new competitive environment.
Institutional Arguments and Issues
Let me now turn to the institutional argument for including
labor provisions in trade agreements and in the
WTO. This is eminently pragmatic. It is the idea that
the ILO has no “teeth”, that is, no enforcement power,
while the WTO and trade agreements do. Several questions
emerge here: Is the enforcement capacity of the
ILO really as weak as sometimes portrayed, and if so,
can it be improved? Can the WTO really be a better
enforcer than the ILO? Which institution could be more
effective in local-capacity building in this area?
On the first question, the view of the Commission of the
European Communities for example, is that “The
ILO has in recent years enhanced very substantially its
means for promoting respect for core labour
standards” (Commission, 2001, p 13). There has been an
important clarification in the position of the
Commission over the past two years. While in Seattle the
Commission seemed to be interested in involving
the WTO in Labor issues, the 2001 European Community proposal
for promoting labor standards is based
on strengthening the ILO’s role.
The EU proposal (Commission, 2001) is quite different from
some of the mainstream positions in the U.S.
debate on these issues. The proposal has a number of basic
tenets:
• rejection of any sanctions-based approaches;
• the principle “that the comparative advantage of countries,
particularly low-wage developing countries,
must in no way be put into question”;
• the idea that “poverty, poor governance and extensive
informal sectors are often the main cause of the
weak implementation of core labour standards in developing
countries”;
• and the notion that “sustained economic growth can contribute
to the respect and effective application of
labour standards and of the social regulatory framework
and vice versa”.
Based on these premises the EU initiative proposes an approach
to promote core labor standards and
improve social governance that “comprises instruments
and actions within different policy fields”. A central
pillar of this integrated strategy is making the ILO a
more effective enforcer by giving more weight to
observations in reports; giving greater publicity to the
supervisory mechanism; improving the effectiveness of
complaint procedures; and consideration of positive incentives.
But there are also other elements in the proposal: increased
multilateral technical assistance, including the
ILO; launching a forum for international dialogue; increasing
trade incentives through the generalized system
of preferences; addressing the issue in bilateral relations
through assistance and capacity strengthening;
supporting private and voluntary schemes for the promotion
of core labor standards through social labeling
and industry codes of conduct.
IV. Why are Most Latin American Countries Opposed
to a Sanctions-Based
Approach?
Now, why are most LAC countries opposed to include labor
provisions in the WTO and in regional trade
agreements, particularly under any approach involving
trade restrictions or sanctions?
To be brief, let me just enumerate the six types of reasons I identify for this opposition:
1. The fear that such inclusion will distract attention
and energies away from the main market access
negotiating priorities of developing countries.
2. The perception that beyond the morality-driven human
rights groups, the pressures to include labor
provisions emanate from politically powerful lobbying
groups, concerned about competitiveness, and
interested in defending protection and privileges.
3. Various issues related to stage of development differences,
particularly the problems with the strict
application of uniform labor standards in very different
labor market conditions.
4. Questions concerning the logic of trade negotiations,
in particular, the fact that given the enormous
asymmetries in market size and relative importance as
trading partners, only countries with large markets
could threaten with credibility and actually produce damage,
in many cases disproportionate damage, by
closing their markets to others. Thus accepting a link
to market access is seen as a way of institutionalising
unilateralism in a multilateral context. No win-win outcome
is perceived in this.
5. The fifth source of opposition is related to the questions:
Are trade sanctions the best way to achieve
results in improving labor standards or other social conditions?
Are there superior ways? Many see
institutional deficiencies as the main obstacle and therefore
consider cooperation through technical assistance
and capacity building as first-best instruments to achieve
results. Institutional deficiencies have been in fact
one of the major difficulties for developing countries
to implement some aspects of trade agreements,
particularly in resource-intensive areas, which suggests
that it is not enough to write a trade provision to
ensure compliance. As the World Bank Global Economic Prospects
Report 2002 points out, trade
agreement implementation requires to step up very substantially
global cooperation outside of the WTO and
outside of trade agreements.
6. Finally, there are arguments related to the architecture
of the global trading system that many developing
countries share but are part of a much wider debate. Trade
negotiators and many experts are concerned
about overloading the WTO, in particular, the dispute
settlement body with disputes that are rather about
labor or environmental issues than about trade. Many believe
that the WTO has neither the expertise nor the
legitimacy to adjudicate these disputes and that asking
it to arbitrate in such matters undermines its credibility
and diverts attention from its first priority, opening-up
markets and enforcing free trade rules. I am personally
quite attracted to the idea of having a more decentralized
system in the allocation of global regulatory
responsibilities, where each agenda is pursued by a separate
responsible agency, with appropriate
coordination between them.
But the point is that for all these reasons the developing
countries have been resisting the inclusion of labor
provisions in the WTO and in trade agreements generally,
particularly under any approach involving trade
restrictions. The outcome of Doha represents a success
for the developing countries on this issue and a
disappointment for certain groups in the US and the EU.
In Doha the labor and environmental issues took different
roads: while there is now a strengthened mandate
to negotiate certain environmental issues,2 on labor
issues in Doha Ministers reaffirmed the Singapore
position that the ILO is the competent body to set and
deal with labor standards and limited themselves to
“take note of work under way in the ILO on the social
dimension of globalization” (Doha Declaration,
paragraph 8). So it is to be expected that at least for
the next few years, and specifically for this round of
multilateral trade negotiations, the Doha Declaration
put to rest the contentious aspects of the trade-labor
nexus issue as a major divider between the developed and
developing worlds in multilateral negotiations.
V. Regional Innovation on Trade and Labor Issues
Given this outcome in Doha, and building on existing trends,
however, it is probable that the labor issue will
be retaken at the regional level, particularly at least
in the Americas.
Despite general opposition to linking, some countries in
Latin America have agreed to include labor
provisions in the regulatory framework of reciprocal trade
agreements. Three models of labor cooperation
agreements have emerged in the Americas, all of them in
the form of side agreements to three trade
agreements: the NAFTA (1994), the Canada-Chile Agreement
(1996) and the Canada-Costa Rica
Agreement (2001). The first two agreements share many
characteristics and procedures; the last one is
more unique, simpler and broader at the same time.
The last section of the paper compares these three labor
cooperation agreements (LCA) in terms of their
objectives; scope; cooperation activities; institutional
mechanisms; procedures for consultation, evaluation
and dispute resolution; and implementation and enforcement.
Let me mention just a few key points:
1. The objective of all three agreements is the promotion
of compliance with and effective enforcement by
each Party of its own labor law, they do not establish
minimum or common standards for domestic law. 3
2. Scope of application is one of the most important differences
between these agreements. The three
agreements cover a broad list of labor rights listed in
an Annex to each agreement. However, only the
political consultations and evaluation process covers
this complete list, the independent review panel or
“arbitral panel” process for dispute resolution is much
more narrow in scope in the North American
Agreement on Labor Cooperation (NAALC) and the Canada-Chile
LCA. The NAALC and the
Canada-Chile agreement limit the scope of the arbitral
panel to the Party’s technical labor standards on
occupational safety and health, child labor or minimum
wage. In contrast, the “review panel” process of the
Canada-Costa Rica LCA has competence to review issues
pertaining to all the rights recognized in the ILO
Declaration on Fundamental Principles and Rights at Work,
1998, which means that it has competence over
a much broader set of issues. In an interview with a high
official in the Canadian Ministry of Labor I was told
this was one of the main features Canadian Trade Unions
had found most attractive in exchange for the
NAFTA-minus nature of the Canada-Costa Rica LCA, in that
it has no trade-sanctions.
3. The three agreements commit the parties to wide ranging
cooperation in specific labor areas and instruct
direct coordination between the labor authorities in each
party.
4. Another difference is that the NAALC as well as the
Canada-Chile Agreement LCA have a long and
complex procedure for consultations, evaluations, and
resolution of disputes. (Box 1). The Canada-Costa
Rica LCA simplifies these procedures. (Box 2).
5. An interesting innovation in the Canada-Costa Rica LCA
is that the Panel is asked to “take into account
(in its recommendations) the existing differences in the
level of development and size of the economies of the
Parties”. No such provision is found in the other two
agreements.
6. Enforcement is the other major difference between agreements.
In the NAALC and the Canada-Chile
LCA, the panel may impose a monetary enforcement assessment
or fine, no greater than 20 million US
dollars in the NAALC and US $ 10 million in the Canada-Chile
LCA. In the NAALC where a Party fails to
pay the fine, the other Party “may suspend NAFTA benefits
in an amount no greater than that sufficient to
collect the monetary enforcement assessment”. In the Canada-Chile
LCA, in contrast, no suspension of
trade benefits –trade sanctions-- is contemplated. Instead
jurisdictional procedures ensure the payment of
fines. The Canada-Costa Rica LCA has neither monetary
enforcement –fines– nor suspension of trade
benefits. It is only established that the party “may take
reasonable and appropriate measures, exclusive of
fines or any measure affecting trade, but including the
modification of cooperative activities (art. 12), to
encourage the other Party to remedy that persistent pattern,
in keeping with the panel’s determinations and
recommendations” (Art. 23, 5)
That is, the Canada-Costa Rica agreement introduces a new
approach based exclusively on cooperation
and technical assistance to promote compliance and effective
enforcement of national labor law.
I do not think that these innovations in RTAs in the Americas
are necessarily relevant in the multilateral
context, particularly in light of the outcome of Doha
on labor issues. However, they have been very
influential in the debates on Trade Promotion Authority
in the US Congress and in the negotiations to create
a Free Trade Area of the Americas.
Let me conclude by stressing the broad global consensus
that exists around the view that the regulatory
framework of globalization should have a set of universally
agreed human rights regarding labor conditions.
At the global level, the post-Doha agenda settled this
issue in favor of allocating global regulatory
responsibilities in the ILO. However, as I suggested,
how this issue will play out in regional governance,
institutions and trade agreements is still an open question.
References
Aggarwal, Mita (1995) International trade, labor standards,
and labor market conditions: an evaluation of
the linkages. U.S. International Trade Commission, Office
of Economics, Working Paper No. 95-06-C,
June.
Brown, Drusilla (2001) "Labor Standards: Where Do They
Belong on the International Trade Agenda?", in
The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol 15, Number 3,
Summer 2001.
Commission of the European Communities (2001) Promoting
Core Labour Standards and Improving Social
Governance in the Context of Globalization, Communication
from the Commission to the Council, the
European Parliament and the Economic and Social Committee,
Brussels.
http://europa.eu.int/comm/trade/pdf/comcls_en.pdf
Dollar, David, and Aart Kraay (2000) “Growth is Good for the Poor”, mimeo, World Bank.
Feenstra, Robert C. (editor) (2000) The Impact of International
Trade on Wages, National Bureau of
Economic Research, The University of Chicago Press, Chicago
and London.
Frankel, Jeffrey, and David Romer (1999) “Does Trade Cause
Growth?”, The American Economic
Review, 89(3): 379-399.
Interamerican Conference of Labor Ministers, Declarations
and Plans of Action – see
www.oas.org/udse/labor.htm
Irwin, Douglas, and Marko Tervio (2000) “Does Trade Raise
Income? Evidence from the Twentieth
Century”, National Bureau of Economic Research, Working
Paper 7745, June.
http://www.nber.org/papers/w7745
Levine, Ross, and David Renelt (1992) “A Sensitivity Analysis
of Cross-Country Growth Regressions”,
American Economic Review, 82(4): 942-63.
Maskus, Keith E. (2000) “Regulatory Standards in the WTO:
Comparing Intellectual Property Rights with
Competition Policy, Environmental Protection and Core
Labor Standards”, University of Colorado,
Boulder. http://www.worldbank.org/wbiep/trade/Standards/wtostandards.pdf
Maskus, K. (1997) “Should Core Labor Standards Be Imposed
through International Trade Policy?” The
World Economy 20, No. 6, September. Also available in:
http://www.worldbank.org/research/trade/wp1817.html
OECD (2000) International Trade and Core Labour Standards, OECD Publications, Paris.
OECD (1996) Trade, Employment and Labour Standards: A Study
of Core Workers’ Rights and
International Trade, OECD Publications, Paris.
Rodríguez, Francisco, and Dani Rodrik, “Trade Policy
and Economic Growth: A Skeptic’s Guide to the
Cross-National Evidence”, NBER Working Paper 7081, April
Rodrik, Dani (2001) “Development Strategies for the Next
Century”, paper Presented at ECLAC-CEPAL
Raul Prebisch Anniversary Conference, August, Santiago,
Chile.
(www.ecla.org/prensa/noticias/comunicados/6/7616/DaniRodrik29-08.pdf)
Rodrik, Dani (1996) “Labour Standards in International
Trade: Do They Matter and What Do We Do
About Them?” In Robert Z. Lawrence, Dani Rodrik and John
Whalley, Emerging Agenda for Global Trade:
High Stakes for Developing Countries. Washington, D.C.:
Overseas Development Council.
Sachs, Jeffrey, and Andrew Warner (1995) “Economic Reform
and the Process of Global Integration,”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 1-118.
Salazar-Xirinachs, J.M. (2000) “The Trade-Labor Nexus:
Developing Countries’ Perspectives”, Journal of
International Economic Law, Vol 3, issue 2.
World Bank (2001) Global Economic Prospects and the Developing
Countries. Making Trade Work for
the World’s Poor, The World Bank, Washington D.C.
NOTES:
(*) Director, Trade Unit, Organization of American States
(jsalazar@oas.org). The views expressed are
those of the author and should not be attributed to the
Organization of American States or to its member
states. This Lecture draws from the paper “Trade, Labor
and Global Governance: A Perspective from the
Americas”, written jointly with Jorge Mario Martínez.
[1] Two bodies of empirical literature support the
general case for the beneficial growth effects trade and economic
openness. One is the recent research that provides evidence
about the positive relationship between trade and growth.
The other is the literature analyzing various integration
and trade liberalization scenarios in Latin America using
multi-country Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) models.
On the former see Levine and Renault (1992), Sachs and
Warner (1995), Sala-i-Martin (1997), Frankel and Romer
(1999), Irwin and Tervio (2000), Dollar and Kraay (2000). Rodriguez
and Rodrik (2000) and Rodrik (2001) are skeptical about
the robustness of some of these results regarding the relationship
between trade openness and growth. Jones (2000), however,
focusing on trade policy variables, concludes that trade
restrictions are almost invariably harmful to long-run
growth, although the magnitude of the effect is uncertain. For Rodrik
“The appropriate conclusion to draw … is not that trade
protection should be preferred to trade liberalization as a rule.
The point is simply that the benefits of trade openness
should not be oversold” (Rodrik, 2001, p 39).
[2] The Doha Declaration contains a mandate to negotiate
three specific issues: (1) the relationship between WTO rules
and trade obligations set out in multilateral environmental
agreements (MEAs); (2) procedures for information exchange
between MEA Secretariats and relevant WTO committees,
and the criteria for the granting of observer status; and (3) the
reduction or elimination of tariff and non-tariff barriers
to environmental goods and services. There is also mandated
discussion in the Committee on Trade and Environment on:
(1) clarifying WTO rules in relation to the effects of
environmental measures on market access; environmental
provisions under the TRIPS agreement such as the patenting of
life forms and the relationship of TRIPS with the U.N.
Convention on Biodiversity; and eco-labelling.
[3] The three agreements have an annex where the
following labor principles are listed: (1) Freedom of association and
protection of the right to organize; (2) The right to
bargain collectively; (3) The right to strike; (4) Prohibition of forced
labor; (5) Labor protections for children and young persons;
(6) Minimum employment standards; (7) Elimination of
employment discrimination; (8) Equal pay for women and
men; (9) Prevention of occupational injuries and illnesses; (10)
Compensation in cases of occupational injuries and illnesses;
(11) Protection of migrant workers.